Disclaimer: Some postings contain other author's material. All such material is used here for fair use and discussion purposes.

Thursday, January 14, 2016

How to Get Rid of Your Landlord and Socialize American Housing, in 3 Easy Steps - By Jesse A. Myerson

Found here. Our comments in bold.
----------------------

Let’s get rid of private housing.

Plenty of time and effort have lately gone into analyzing a host of related crises—homelessness, unaffordable urban real estate, devastating gentrification, (Which is the renewal of poor and run down neighborhoods, which cause and influx of people and an accompanying increase in values. This pushes out the original, poor residents. The Leftist blog Slate thinks it's mostly a myth.

It's interesting to us that the Left is offended by the idea of old, run-down neighbors being revitalized.)

and a housing bubble whose burst landed us in the Great Recession. But the explanations tend to be incomplete, the attributions shortsighted, and the policies rearguard. For every liberal who insists that deregulating zoning laws will curb skyrocketing urban housing prices, there’s a conservative who blames the 1977 Community Reinvestment Act for the housing bubble, and none of them is anywhere near the mark. (We shall see if the author, a self-described Socialist, ever mentions the devastating role government played in the Great Recession.)

The true culprit is so deeply embedded in American notions of wealth, rights, and property that we cannot see it for the terrible economy policy it is: private housing. Real estate as a store of private wealth is the rotten tree that sprouts these diseased branches, and the solution is to quit pruning twigs and chop the sucker down. (Hmm. So the problem is people owning property. Apparently, if no one owned property, then gentrification, homelessness, and the housing bubble wouldn't have happened. This of course is impossible to know, and in fact is a preposterous assertion. 

SOMEONE will own the property. If not a private party, it's government. And we have no evidence whatsoever that government ownership of property has ever been successful.)

I’ll propose some models and policies that can do the trick, but first—what is private housing, exactly?

First off, it is mostly land. That is, real estate is the most valuable asset form in the United States, and the majority of that value is not that of the building itself, which depreciates until it requires renovation, but of the “unimproved” land it sits on—the location. Imagine a skyscraper filled with sumptuous luxury condominiums, located in the center of Antarctica: However many millions had gone into its cutting-edge furnishings, without a community (parks, transit options, schools, shops, etc.) around to situate it in a desirable location, that building would be worthless as a real-estate investment. These community resources are reflected in what is commonly called “land value,” but is more precisely the price of the location. Rather than flowing to the community that created it, however, it is captured by individual real-estate owners. (The author tells us that land is where the value is, but a vacant piece of land has much less value than a piece of land with a useful structure on it. 

Location of course can make a piece of land more valuable. But it's only valuable because of what can be built on it. No one would build a hi-rise in Antarctica because it makes no sense economically. There is no demand for a hi-rise in Antarctica because there are no people there.

Again, the value of land is inextricably tied to what can be done with it, not the fact that it exists.)

More fundamentally, though, what we call private housing is actually public land that government has set aside for private purposes. (Incorrect. Ownership claims to land pre-date government. Government ownership is not the default state.)

Land, save the bits beneath one’s feet, can’t be “possessed,” as a phone or a shirt can. What a “land owner” possesses is a deed—a voucher one may redeem with the government to marshal violence (through policing) to exclude all competing claimants. (No, a deed acknowledges the legality of the ownership claim to the property. It is just as much a possession as a phone or shirt is, in fact, more so. 

It is interesting that the author claims that a deed does not mean ownership, but a phone or a shirt can be owned without the need for a deed. This is a strange argument. If anything, the legal documentation of ownership by deed establishes possession indisputably. 

And we might note that vehicles are titled, again an acknowledgment by government of the ownership of the vehicle. Would the author claim a vehicle is cannot be possessed because there is a government-issued document describing it?

The more you think about it, the more convoluted is the author's reasoning. He's claiming in essence that you don't own something until the government says you do. This of course is false. If you purchase a home, your ownership rights transfer on the day of closing. The deed is issued subsequent to you taking ownership of the property.

Finally, there is no violence involved in having a legally-confirmed claim to ownership. Or does a claim to ownership of a cellphone require violence to assert ownership?)

The government established this location-exclusion program, designating pieces of nature as being solely for the use of the deed holders, and devoting its violent capabilities to enforcing that designation. (No, the government acknowledged the existing ownership of property. Its "violent capabilities" are not violent at all, they are actually the enforcement of the law. That's what government does, enforce the law. Government supplies order and uniformity to the ownership of property by documenting its deed holders as the owners.

Apparently the author believes one cannot own "pieces of nature." Yet he appears to believe that one can own a shirt or a phone. The difference is elusive. He makes no effort to explain himself, preferring to continue his narrative without establishing his assertions in any way.)

In the 19th century, the government enacted homesteading laws to allow frontier settlers to claim indigenous lands as their own. If those deeds were challenged, the federal government sent troops to back them up. (Um, no. If a deed is challenged, it is a legal proceeding where the parties appear before a court or other government body, which examines the claims of each party. The deed documents the fact that the deed holder is the owner, and thus all other claims are deemed invalid. Should other parties persist in contesting the ownership, it may indeed require law enforcement, a just power of government.)

Or look at the 20th century, when the government funded highways and commuter transit—the Federal Housing Administration extended loan guarantees to new housing developments in order to create a massive suburban private-housing stock. The entire apparatus by which housing is privately “owned” is created by the government’s decisions to subsidize or protect certain interests. (No, the apparatus is subsequent to the ownership of property. Property rights are unalienable, and a fundamental feature of a free people.

Further, government overstepped its constitutional authority by granting loan guarantees. This violated the marketplace and caused negative eventualities that rippled through the market.)

Ostensibly, the government pursues the public interest, (Government does not pursue "the public interest." It acknowledges individual interests and enforces the law in that regard.)

but treating real estate as privately owned wealth, as a financial asset, has devastating public effects. (There are no such things as "public effects." The "public" has no legal claim on the private interests of individuals, except to the degree those interests violate the property rights of others.)

On a grand scale, treating land as an asset allows speculators to create bubbles large enough to threaten global economic collapse. The housing bubble—really a land bubble—of the last decade bid the price of land up so high, concocting such dangerous “complex financial instruments” to turn out so many sub-prime mortgages, that the burst was enough to sink some of the world’s most profitable firms, plunge us into the Great Recession, extinguish the majority of all black wealth in the United States, bankrupt pension funds worldwide, and destroy the governments of Greece, Iceland, and other nations. (A truly inventive fable is concocted by the author. The economic collapse was felt across the world, no matter the system of government in place. For America, it was, by and large, a consequence of government interventions, which accumulated into a burden too great for the economy to bear.

Couple that with government's tendency to coddle large corporations and pay them off with bailouts, sweetheart deals, favorable regulations, and laws not equally applied, and we have a recipe for disaster.


But more to the point, there were indeed laws broken by the financial sector of the economy, and government is charged with "violently" protecting the rights of its citizens. Obama did nothing. Thus, this is a failure of government to enforce the law and maintain justice. 

Further, those misdeeds are offered by the author as prima facie evidence for the need to end property rights, as if that was the entirety of private property behavior. But for every misdeed of a large property owner, there are thousands of homeowners legally pursuing their private interests regarding their homes. Yet according to the author, individuals don't really own their homes and must cede their property rights too.)

Closer to home, private ownership of land underlies racist segregation. The aforementioned FHA policy, for instance, designed to protect homeowners’ access to gains in their houses’ location value, provided white people with the incentive to take their capital and flee urban centers for sprawling exurban developments, (Wait, I thought it was gentrification. Now the author says that the opposite is happening?)

there to adopt racial exclusivity covenants, in order to prevent black people from moving in and undermining the location price—thus, the plot of A Raisin in the Sun. (This is a preposterous assertion. The author claims that owning and holding property, and then selling it for a profit, is racist. On what basis does he assert this? An apocryphal observation that people adopted "racial exclusivity covenants!" We would love to see a homeowners association document that says, "white people only." Until then, the authors claims are dismissed.

Also worthy of note is the obvious fact that the author must clearly reside in a large metropolitan area, which is a terribly narrow sample from which he draws his conclusions. However, his experience is insufficient to assert broad policy recommendations, as if all of the country is exactly like inner-city New York.)

In the resulting “inner city,” which the public Home Owners’ Loan Corporation “red-lined” on its residential security maps, black people who were locked out of “middle-class” neighborhoods were conscripted to capital-starved, decaying ghettos, where parasitic slumlords reigned supreme. (Ah, so this is why black people live in the ghettos! And there are absolutely no middle class blacks. Eeevil banks and slumlords! Does the fact that people are poor and are on public assistance have anything to do with the fact that they live in inner city subsidized housing and have no money to move out of the ghettos have any bearing on the issue?)

Finally, developers have an incentive to snap up urban land and then leave it vacant until it appreciates in value, driven by community development around it, and then sell it. Meanwhile, residents have to live with the social repercussions of a community riddled with vacant lots. (Except many city governments have requirements about vacant lots.

But the real problem apparently is that property appreciates and it is somehow immoral to hold a property and sell it for a profit. The author never tells us why this is wrong.)

What to do?

There are a few ways to turn land and housing stock toward the public good.

An exclusion fee

For a start, everyone should be compensated for their exclusion from passage over certain locations on the earth. (Of course! We are quivering with admiration! The first thing the author proposes is a tax.)

To do this, we ought to levy an exclusion fee whereby the location price of the property in question would be returned to its rightful recipient, the community. As long as land value is socially created and land ownership is duty-free, a theft is occurring. (Land value is not created by anyone. It is a natural consequence of market forces. Society does not own the land, the land is owned by the owner, and as such possesses the right to do with it as he pleases, as long as it is for a legal purpose.)

The idea for such a fee was most famously advocated by political economist Henry George in his book Progress and Poverty, under the name “single tax” or “land-value tax.” (That is, a tax to use your own property. Like... a property tax!)

Several municipalities in George’s native Pennsylvania have a version of it: a two-tiered property tax, wherein the assessed value of the location is taxed at a higher rate than the assessed value of the building. For best results, 100 percent of the location price should be confiscated and invested in a sovereign wealth fund, the way Alaska’s oil royalties are. That fund could either pay out universal dividends, the way the Alaska Permanent Fund does, or provide the public with a huge pool of resources with which to invest in public institutions. How huge? Michael Hudson estimates that the land value of New York City alone is greater than the total combined worth of the entire country’s productive infrastructure. (?? The land value of New York city is a product of capitalism. It will have no value at all if it is confiscated by government.)

An exclusion fee effectively makes the land public, leaving the “owners” of the buildings without a way to collect more in rental income than the building, distinct from the land, is worth. (Ah, the tacit admission that government will steal the land from the owner by levying punitive taxes against the owner. Really, what could go wrong?

Hmm, setting the rental rate sounds like, um, rent control? Like what New York already does?)

Community land trusts

But why endow private profit-motivated interests control over construction at all? There is no reason to suspect that a given property-development capitalist should be more capable of determining for a community what optimally desirable new buildings to produce than the community itself is. (That is, government is eminently more qualified to determine the best use of your property. You're not.)

Luckily, there is an entity capable of turning development over to the most concerned parties: nonprofit community land trusts, their boards typically composed at least one-third of residents, take land off the market, and lease homes long-term to residents at below-market rates, retaining the majority of the home equity gained over time. (That is, voluntary associations of people, uncoerced by government, make decisions in their own best interests regarding their properties.)

The predominantly black and Latino residents of the Dudley Street area of Roxbury, one of Boston’s poorest neighborhoods, got Boston city officials to take the unprecedented step of granting the power of eminent domain to the community for more than 1,300 parcels of abandoned land. With this tract, the Dudley Street Neighborhood Initiative (DSNI) established a community land trust that has democratically directed a renovation project resulting in hundreds of affordable-housing units and other public spaces, among them community centers, new schools, a community greenhouse, parks, and playgrounds. ("Granted permission." In other words, government got out of the way and let the people decide to do what they wanted with the properties.)

While the rest of Boston has lately struggled with a blight of post-bubble vacancies, followed by a massive wave of turn-overs due to rising rents, residents of DSNI’s land trust maintained a stable community. Most of the first batch of houses sold on the trust still contain their initial owners, who are passing them on to their children.(Hmm. That's sounds suspiciously like they own the properties.)

“If you’re looking to buy a house, flip it, and speculate elsewhere,” says Tony Hernandez, longtime resident and director of operations for the land trust, “you’d better move on, because that’s not what this is intended for.”

Public housing

Ultimately, though, the best antidote to private housing is public housing. Unfortunately, the result of American city planners’ contempt for poor and especially black people is clear: squalid conditions, severe architecture, and placement of public housing in neighborhoods starved for educational, healthcare, and other crucial resources. (Yes, government has done it so well in the past, they should do even more.)

It is common in the United States to suppose that these conditions are a byproduct of cultural defects particular to black and other poor people. As community organizer Karen Narefsky writes, “While few would blame potholed roads on the drivers who use them, a great effort has been made to attribute the degeneration of public housing in the US to public housing residents themselves.” (Because the residents have no interest at stake in the properties, they have no motivation to maintain them. This is the inevitable result of the policies the author advocates.)

But public housing needn’t be this way, as the Vienna model attests. Owing to its erstwhile socialist government (“Red Vienna,” 1918–34), the City of Vienna is the largest landowner in all of Austria. On its land, the city government provides comfortable housing (whose units might be high-end condos in the United States) not just to poor and working-class people but to virtually half the city. Public housing accounts for more than 13 times the housing overseen by the affordable-housing agency of Philadelphia, a city with a comparable population size. The public-housing system established Vienna’s first libraries, and many of its kindergartens, daycare centers, dental clinics, and parks. “These places are incredible,” architectural historian William Menking is quoted as saying. “There are swimming pools and saunas and bicycle parking.” (Hooray, Vienna has a success! One success compared to thousands of failures in the US.)

Moreover, while a private capitalist-driven housing system must prioritize cost over all other considerations, (This fellow really doesn't understand capitalism, which makes all his prescriptions invalid. There is no "capitalist-driven housing system," there are simply people living their daily lives, building housing as the market demands, and making a profit in the transaction. 

Costs are not prioritized above all things, marketability is. There is no benefit to the builder to construct a cheap house if it will not sell.

The author would prefer to ascribe nefarious motives to them in order to puff up his supposed solutions. But there is nothing nefarious in voluntary exchange of value.)

the Vienna model situates expense amid three other equally weighted factors: architectural quality, environmental performance, and social sustainability. (In other words, it substitutes one set of values for others based on its own preferences and goals.)

This forecloses, if the expression can be excused, the possibility of the sort of ghettoization that has been endemic in US public-housing programs. To emulate the Vienna model here, significant federal funding (Via confiscatory taxes, of course.)

should be provided to municipalities to buy land (or claim it by eminent domain), and build gigantic stocks of public housing, with a specific emphasis on environmental soundness, and diversity of class and ethnic background.

* * *

The Dudley Street Neighborhood Initiative transformed more than 32 acres of land in Boston from commodity to community. Regarding how it was able to perform this transformation, and how it has successfully resisted an economic system that greedily militates for land to be privatized, Eliza Parad, a DSNI community organizer, cites “the political power this community, a majority community of color, has built since the 1970s.” As the lives of the Dudley Street neighbors testify, land removed from the private market, de-commodified, and placed under the ownership and management of the people who live there is land that creates and renews its own political constituency.

Likewise, the Vienna model of public and publicly managed housing is politically insulated, because it encompasses nearly half the city. In US cities, the residents of public-housing projects constitute a small minority of easily marginalized and maligned poor people, ill-equipped to do battle with landed interests. Thus, Baltimore offers millions in tax breaks to developers to buy up the public housing stock, while the working-class Viennese residents of Karl Marx Court enjoy their saunas.

Gentrification, home-mortgage bubbles, homelessness, skyrocketing rent—these are not facts of nature. (No, they are facts of incessant government meddling.)

They are the outcomes of the policies that consign the basic human need of location to the whims of rent-obsessed landlords and chop-licking speculators looking for an easy flip. Private land policies are as evil today as they were almost 4 centuries ago when the Pilgrims near Bridgewater, Massachusetts, arrested Wampanoag people for hunting on a tract of land after the Pilgrims had “purchased” it. “What is this you call property?” the sachem, Massasoit, argued on that occasion. “It cannot be the earth, for the land is our Mother…. everything on it belongs to everybody and is for the use of all. How then can one man say it belongs to him only?” There was no satisfactory retort then, and there isn’t one now. (Of course there's a "satisfactory retort." We don't have to accept this native American religious tenet simply because the author quotes it. What they believe about the land is irrelevant.)

No comments:

Post a Comment