I’m the enemy, ’cause I like to think; I like to read. I’m into freedom of speech and freedom of choice. I’m the kind of guy who likes to sit in a greasy spoon and wonder, “Gee, should I have the T-bone steak or the jumbo rack of barbecued ribs with the side order of gravy fries?” ...Why? Because I suddenly might feel the need to, okay, pal? -Edgar Friendly, character in Demolition Man (1993).
Disclaimer: Some postings contain other author's material. All such material is used here for fair use and discussion purposes.
Tuesday, July 29, 2014
The Full Employment Route to Poverty Reduction - by Dean Baker
This post originally appeared at TalkPoverty.org. Posted here for fair use and discussion purposes. My comments in bold.
-------------------------------
Efforts to alleviate poverty are often seen as being separate from the debate on overall economic policy, with the former involving a distinct set of issues that only marginally overlap with the latter. This is unfortunate, since the health of the economy and specifically the level of unemployment, has an enormous impact on the prospects of the poor. In fact, there are few policies that are likely to have as much effect on improving the plight of the poor or near poor as a genuine commitment to full employment economic policies. (Commitment by whom? You will discover the governo-centric perspective is all that will be considered by the writer. Like most Leftists, the writer believes solutions to society's problems all come from government programs.)
There are three separate channels through which a reduction in the unemployment rate is likely to benefit low-income people. The first is simply by increasing their probability of finding jobs. Unemployment is not evenly distributed throughout the workforce; the less-educated and disadvantaged see the sharpest rises in unemployment when the economy goes into a downturn. (Because they are the least qualified and least productive. More highly trained and experienced workers, though they lose their jobs, are more likely to be able to find a replacement job, even at a lower wage, whereas the lowest skilled workers have nowhere to go.)
In the year prior to the beginning of the recession, the unemployment rate for workers without a high school degree averaged just over 7.0 percent. Its average for 2010 was 14.8 percent, an increase of 7.8 percentage points.
In the year prior to the beginning of the recession, the unemployment rate for workers without a high school degree averaged just over 7.0 percent. Its average for 2010 was 14.8 percent, an increase of 7.8 percentage points. For workers with high school degrees the unemployment rate went from 4.3 percent to 10.3 percent, a rise of 6.0 percentage points. By contrast, the unemployment rate for college grads rose by just 2.7 percentage points, from 2.0 percent to 4.7 percent. While everyone got hit by the downturn, clearly those with less education saw the greatest increase in their risk of being unemployed.
There is a similar story about race. The unemployment rate for whites rose from 4.1 percent in the years before the downturn to 8.7 percent in 2010, a rise of 4.6 percentage points. The unemployment rate for African-Americans rose from 8.2 percent to 16.0 percent in 2010, a rise of 7.8 percentage points. The unemployment rate for Hispanics went from 5.6 percent before the downturn to 12.5 percent, an increase of 6.9 percentage points. (I wonder if the writer is able to make the connection that President Obama has presided over this unfortunate situation?)
There are various explanations as to why less educated and African American and Hispanic workers see the sharpest rise in unemployment during downturns, but there is little debate about this outcome. Also, there is no evidence of any change in this pattern as the economy has recovered, despite the claims of some analysts.
For the first five months of 2014 the unemployment rate for workers without high school degrees averaged 9.5 percent, a drop of 5.3 percentage points from 2010 levels. The unemployment rate for college grads averaged 3.3 percent, a decline of 1.4 percentage points from recession peaks. This means the least educated workers have actually made more progress in getting back to pre-recession unemployment rates than the most educated workers. If the unemployment rate were to return to pre-recession levels for the population as a whole, it would almost certainly fall back to pre-recession levels for the less educated and minorities as well. (Here we have a conclusion based on the idea that there is a recovery, and that this recovery has manifested in returning to the former levels and kinds of employment. I suppose that because of the unabashed cheerleading in the media about the wonderful results of Obama's economic policies, the writer actually believes there is a recovery. However, the great majority of jobs added are service jobs, which means that low-skill workers aren't going to get those jobs. As stated above, higher skill workers who lost their jobs have taken them.)
In addition to the unemployment channel, workers at the bottom of the income ladder are also likely to benefit from low unemployment as a result of having the opportunity to work more hours. In my book with Jared Bernstein, Getting Back to Full Employment (free download available), we show that the late 1990s boom was associated with an increase of 17 percent in the total number of hours worked for households in the bottom fifth of the income distribution. By contrast, the increase in hours worked for households in the top two income quintiles was just 1.0 percent. There are many low-income people who would like to be able to put in more hours on the job. The low unemployment of the late 1990s, which bottomed out at 4.0 percent as a year-round average in 2000, provided this opportunity.
If full employment of the sort that we saw at the end of the 1990s could be sustained for a long period of time, it would almost certainly lead to a substantial reduction in poverty rates and a large improvement in living standards for low-income people. (Duh. So people being able to work lowers poverty? Who da thunk?)
Finally, low unemployment provides workers at the middle and bottom of the wage distribution with the bargaining power they need to get a share of the economy’s growth. Hourly wages have been largely stagnant for these workers for most of the last three decades. (All the way up through the upper middle class, in fact. The writer seems incurious why that might be.) However, in the years from 1996-2000, workers at the middle and bottom saw substantial wage gains. According to our analysis, a sustained 1.0 percentage point drop in the unemployment rate translates to a 9.8 percent increase in the wages of a worker at the 20th percentile of the wage distribution. It would lead to a wage gain for a worker in the middle of the wage distribution of 4.2 percent. It has little effect on the wages of workers at the top of the income distribution. (Does the writer have any idea why that period was good for employment?)
For these reasons, a full employment policy is an effective way to increase the opportunities and income of people at the bottom. If full employment of the sort that we saw at the end of the 1990s could be sustained for a long period of time, it would almost certainly lead to a substantial reduction in poverty rates and a large improvement in living standards for low-income people.
When the unemployment rate was falling to thirty-year lows in the late 1990s the press had accounts of suburban hotels and restaurants chartering busses to pick workers up in the inner cities and drive them to their jobs in the suburbs. There were stories of employers providing day care facilities and even making arrangements to accommodate elder care for workers caring for aging parents. Some firms actively sought out workers with disabilities. In a tight labor market, firms will make extraordinary efforts to recruit employees whom at other times they would likely not hire.
Full employment is also a desirable policy because it goes directly against the “makers versus takers” line that many conservatives push. (This passing remark, taking a shot at conservatives, constructs a straw man left dangling without context.) Full employment is about giving people at the bottom the opportunity to work. In this same context, not pursuing full employment is effectively a policy of not offering people an opportunity to work. (So far the buzz phrase "full employment" has been tossed about several times, but never has the writer broached the subject of how this functions in the economy. The next sentence, however, contains an astounding explanation of how this will happen.)
This is a crucial point. We can talk about a policy to promote full employment — by investing in infrastructure, spending on retrofitting buildings or solar paneling to reduce greenhouse gas emissions, or subsidizing pre-K education; (Were you able to catch your breath after that? I'm still reeling a bit. Notice that everything in this list is make-work government programs and leftist cause de jours. Nothing here about businesses needing workers because demand has increased [a real indicator of economic recovery]. Nothing about there being a need to hire because businesses are expanding. No mention of legislative environment, tax policy, regulatory changes, or anything that might indicate the writer's understanding about why businesses hire. No, instead the writer wants government programs.) but accepting a higher level of unemployment is also a policy decision. We know that we can get more growth and lower rates of unemployment with more government spending. There is enough research on this topic that it should no longer be a debatable point. (No, we do NOT know this. This is total nonsense. Government money first belonged to the taxpayer. Government must take it from someone before it can spend it. This is simply a reallocation of existing money, where government spends it where it wants rather than the private person choosing his own spending habits. It is the profligate spending of government that has kept a damper on any sort of recovery.
On the contrary, it is government spending that has kept a large number of people destitute and unemployed. We are entering our 6th year of anemic economic growth. Most downturns last 18-24 months, unless government steps in an meddles with its solutions. Then they last years.
Back in the late 90's government was starting to get its deficit spending under control. There was substantial welfare reform. As the writer noted above, unemployment was lower. There were no infrastructure initiatives or government make-work programs to speak of. The economy itself was responding to the very real idea that government was making an effort to get out of the way.
Business values stability, the ability to anticipate whether or not the legal, legislative, and economic policy environment is going to be the same tomorrow as it was yesterday. Business wants to be able to plan and make projections. It doesn't want to be surprised by obamacare-like programs that turn the economic world upside down. Nothing in the current environment inspires the confidence of business. Quite the contrary, business is very careful about risking anything. The situation, the "recovery," simply doesn't warrant taking the risk.)
We can also get lower rates of unemployment by reducing the size of the trade deficit. If we can increase our exports and replace imports with domestically produced goods and services, it will increase output and lead to more jobs. If we were to eliminate the trade deficit altogether and have balanced trade, it would create almost 6 million jobs. The trade deficit is also the result of policy decisions, most importantly ones pertaining to the value of the dollar. A dollar that costs less in foreign currencies makes our goods cheaper for the rest of the world to purchase, and makes imports more expensive. We could make deals with foreign countries to raise the value of their currency against the dollar as President Reagan did with the Plaza Accord in 1985, but our trade policy has taken a different direction. (Sigh. WHY is there a trade deficit? If it costs more to make a product domestically than to buy it from China, isn't in natural for purchasing to shift to China? If because of heavy regulation, complex and stifling taxation, and a whole assortment of other economic factors, businesses shift their purchasing to get the most bang for the buck, why would they make their products here?)
There may be reasons why people want smaller budget deficits, but pushing for deficit reduction in the current economic environment is ultimately a policy of denying people jobs. (No, no, no, no. First, as far as the Left is concerned, there is NEVER good time to reduce deficits. Second, reducing the deficit is not the same as lowering the national debt. Third, government doesn't create jobs. As we noted above, government money is sourced from the private sector. There is no net gain when government employs people.
Fourth, what is the "current economic environment?" Is this a tacit admission that all is not as rosy as we thought? And why is the writer afraid of government getting its economic house in order? Will that be an admission that the economy does much better without the government coming in to "rescue" us? In the same vein, supporting a high dollar, and therefore a large trade deficit, is also a policy of denying people jobs. And, since higher unemployment reduces the bargaining power of workers and leads to lower wages, a high unemployment policy is a policy that provides employers with low-cost labor, exacerbating economic inequality. (The writer doesn't seem to make the connection that if no one is buying, there is no need to make things, and no need to hire people. therefore, an unemployed worker has no bargaining power. If the labor pool is large for the number of potential jobs, the worker either chooses to work at the wage offered, or remains unemployed. The worker should have no power when the economy is faltering.)
In short, a full employment policy is a tremendously effective way to increase the income and opportunities available to the poor and near poor. But the high unemployment policy we currently have in place is one that redistributes income upward and denies people the jobs they need to escape poverty.
Dean Baker is co-director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research in Washington, DC. He previously worked as a senior economist at the Economic Policy Institute and an assistant professor at Bucknell University. His blog, Beat the Press, features commentary on economic reporting. (Whew. Apparently this man is educated. Unfortunately, he seems more maleducated, or perhaps he is unable to separate his leftist politics from his economic understandings. In any event, it just goes to show you that a long list of credentials is no indicator of trustworthiness or competence.)
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment